Social Economy for local governance structures: monitoring and evaluation
perspectives.
Source: Nasioulas I. & Tsobanoglou G. (2004). Social Economy for
local governance structures: monitoring and evaluation perspectives. In: Coccosis H. & Psycharis
Y. (2007). Conference Proceedings of the 46th ERSA Conference. Volos. University of Thessaly. Vol. 1. pp. 337.
Abstract
Social economy, the ground between free market, private benefit institutions, the State
regulation and society, needs to be positively identified. The existing, traditional, monitoring and evaluation
concepts, methods and tools are prooven to ineffectively identify and describe the social conjunctions, adherent to
the social mediation of the economic sphere. Coherent, scientifically valid, approaches need to be formulated. Up
to date methods and tools, capable of reaching and describing the social economy phenomenon, emerge as a useful
contribution, as long as they refrain from the traditional economistic and administrative context. The creation of
a positive, new grammar for the identification of social economy forms the core of our interest. Local governance
structures tend to lean upon such trends as they require partnership organizations to meet successfully local
priorities essential to combat exclusion, poverty, acculturation, community growth and employability. Recent trends
in the evaluation of this strategic field will be provided.
Introduction
The new glocalized environment creates capacities for democratic communities, individuals and
structures of market and the state to collaborate voluntarily, in order to provide community services , empower
civic action and local developement. The Social Economy territory comprises of institutions and organizations of
such an orientation, independent from the market and the state.
Social Economy institutions are multilateral and diversified in form and interest. The
tradional idea of a profit oriented economic organization or a public service institution created a recognition
process, that cannot coincide with the need for a positive identification of Social Economy structures.
The only scientifically and empirically valid approach for an identification context on
Social Economy structures and activities should focus on the priority of discovering and emphasizing on the
specific historical cause and the ethical motivation that gave birth to an initiative , definetely oriented towards
non market and non state community service providing.
Traditional monitoring and evaluation methods are clearly oriented towards an
organizational, economotechnical analysis of structures and activities. The sociological perspective comprises of
approaching all other factors, that contribute to the special character of such Social Economy initiatives and
cannot be displayed through a logistics approach.
Thus, recent trends in the evaluation of this strategic field are provided.
Social Economy and Social Capital
In the new glocalized environment, a sphere of functions and interconnections, between emerging
global stuctures and simultaneous processes, in the local and regional level tends to form (Carayannis & Von
Zedtwitzb , 2005). Citizens and local communities are oriented towards needs, that market economy and the state are
not capable or willing to cover. These needs constitute an emerging territory, between profit oriented economic
activities and state controlled, public oriented , services. Thus, Social Economy emerges (Salamon et al.,1994,
EMES, 1999, La Ville & Nussens, European Commission).
Social Economy istitutions include social enterprises, social cooperatives, unions, mutual
aid and developement funds, civil society organizations and any other form of economically active schemes, that
comply with the following preconditions:
· they are basically non profit, but , even if they create an economic surplus, it
is distributed not to the managers but to the beneficiaries
· they are independent from the state, even if sometimes the state is their main
financier
· their basis is selforganization of the civil society, voluntary action,
reciprocity, cooperation and trust
Empirical research shows that Social Economy institutions tend to focus on quality of life
issues , environmental problem solving , cultural , social and local development , innovation and social welfare
(OECD, 2000, 2001, 2002, EIE , 2002, Τσομπάνογλου, 2002, ICASO, 2002, UNAIDS, 2000, 2002).
The driving force behind Social Economy is Social Capital. Like financial or human capital,
Social Capital is a key factor to economic activities (LEED, 2002, Woolcock, 2000, 2002, Barros, 2001). It refers
to elements of sociability amongst community members, based on the presence of trust, reciprocity, common rules,
official and unofficial social networks and effective chanells of information, which can be mobilized as economical
equivalents by individuals or groups in a community (OECD, Field, 2003, Anders, 1993).
Social Economy and Social Capital literature lie on several fundamental
acknowledgements:
· there exist needs which enterprise interests or state public services either
can’t or are not interested in meeting
· there exist reserves of economically signifiant capital outside the financial
sphere
· economic and social relations tend to create feedback effects between one
another
· there exists an emerging need for a new grammar of development: to the
conventional resources, qualitative elements, intrinsic to human relations, need to be taken into account
In general terms, the basic principle behind Social Economy refers to organized activities
fundamentally oriented towards society, based on democratic values and at the same time, being independent from the
public sector. Such activities are undertaken by associations, cooperatives, clusters (Rosenfeld, 2002, European
Commission), institutions, societies and so on. The basic motive behind the organization of all these activities
and structures is public benefit or the benefit of a specially selecter group of individuals - not profit and
surplus maximization for the investors.
A positive identification of Social Economy
Social Economy institutions are multilateral and diversified in form and interest. The tradional
idea of a profit oriented economic organization or a public service institution created a recognition process that
cannot coincide with the need for a positive identification of Social Economy structures. How is it possible to
deal with the mutliple identities intrinsic in a Social Economy organization? Management literature is not enough.
In fact it is missleading when it comes to social enterprises, cooperatives and so on. The sociological perspective
creates a context of analysis in which the social, economic and organizational identities of Social Economy
structures can be dealt with simultaneously.
Neither the legal form of the organization, nor its field of interest can positively
define its Social Economy nature. Neither its organizational basis, nor its surplus creating capacity are definite
critiria. Social Economy organizations produce characteristics which can be easily found in any other form of
private or public institution. The only scientifically and empirically valid approach for an identification context
on Social Economy structures and activities should focus on the priority of discovering and emphasizing on the
specific historical cause and the ethical motivation that gave birth to an initiative, definetely oriented towards
non market and non state community service providing.
Traditional monitoring and evaluation methods are clearly oriented towards an
organizational, economotechnical analysis of structures and activities. The sociological perspective comprises of
approaching all other factors, that contribute to the special character of such Social Economy initiatives and
cannot be displayed through a logistics approach.
An evaluation context for Social Economy
Contemporary trends in social research reafirm the significance of a combination scheme
between a priori assessments, ongoing monitoring procedures (reviews) and ex post overall evaluations.
Several alternatives exist, as far as evaluation procedures are concerned: self assesments,
participatory, complex methods or meta – evaluations, focusing on any significant issue – field of interest, master
plan, tools, physical, human or social capital, and so on.
This paper introduces a two-fold criterion for Social Economy Organizations Monitoring and
Evaluation. We must develope evaluation methods capable of recognizing signs of effectiveness, on the one hand and
viability, on the other (InnoNet, W.K. Kellogg Foundation, 1998, Connolly & Clein, 1999).
According to traditional perspectives, effectiveness can be measured on the basis of
administratively significant, statute goals and objectives. The sociological perspective, though, stresses upon an
evaluation of the socially significant, actual outputs of an initiative (Table 1).
Table 1. The administrative and the sociological perspective
|
Proceedings Evaluation
|
Outcomes Evaluation
|
Strategic Objective
|
Fullfilment of statute declared goals.
|
Obtention of actual benefit.
|
Advantage
|
What we are interested in , is on the statute.
We have a clear cut masterplan.
Transparency.
|
What we are interested in , is on the field.
Positive feedback can be taken into account.
Adaptability.
|
Disadvantage
|
Conservative Accounts.
No viable consensus on the ethical motives: “stick to what is on the paper”.
|
Hazy Masterplan.
Motives and actions far beyond the scope of the initiative.
|
As far as viability is concerned, we can similarly introduce two aspects: functional
viability and social viability.
Functional viability refers to organizational capacity, funding, infrastructures and so
on. Scarcity of resources intensifies competition between Social Economy institutions, threatening with extinction
stuctures weaker in capacity and scope. Cohabitation and clientelistic relationships tend to emerge, between policy
makers and Social Economy organizations, questioning their independence and consequently threatening their social
legitimacy. Sometimes, harsh competition imposes strict administrative and economic rules, distorting their social
orientation and their perception about costs and benefits.
Distortion of the economic environment, political intemediation and institutional
framework gaps exert a negative influence, even as far as economically viable initiatives are concerned.
Nontheless, let’s bear in mind that the nature of resources social organizations mobilize
is primarily social , not political , legal or economic. Social viability refers to the degree of trust,
institutional transparency, social relations, a culture of cooperation and legitimacy – in other words, social
capital – that exists in the community and is inherent in the Social Economy initiative.
So even when it comes to the “healthy, viable enterprise, in a non healthy, hostile
environment” scenario, evaluation methods and tools should be able to sort out all the qualitative element ,
significant to the sociological perspective.
The true challenge for contemporary social research lies on the formation of elucidating
evaluation methods and tools, capable of unfolding the socially significant aspects of economic and civic
activity.
Evaluation Methods and Tools for Social Economy Institutions
The formation of a monitoring and evaluation plan belongs to the first most significant steps of
creating a Social Economy organization (ICASO, 2002, Adevi Olusoji et al., 2000). The use of qualitative research
methods and tools aims at outlining:
· personal attitudes and contributions
· the functional identity of the organization or initiative
· the difference between personal experiencess of the participants and what is
actually going on
· dynamic elements in the backround of the initiative
Empirical research on Social Economy structures shows the importance of forming a strategic
partners’ alliance, safeguarding the validity and plurality of the evaluation process (UNAIDS, 2000).
Sewell quotes a five step State Strengthening Evaluation Guide (as introduced by Callor, Betts,
Carter & Marczak, 1997) , particularly useful in Social Economy evaluations :
· Clarification and definition (the identity of the programme)
· Accountability (what we say we do , and what is actually being done)
· Comprehension (personal experience from the field of action)
· Results oriented processes (internal assesements and community attitudes)
· Feedback (secondary analysis)
ICASO HIV / AIDS Networking Guide (2002) gives a detailed, step by step, evaluation guide and
Church et al. (2002) introduce the significance of qualitative data providing capacity of the tools we are about to
use: the tailor made questionnaire, “Weaver’s Triangle”, “Contributions Assessment”, “Letters of Commitment”,
“Channels of Participation”, SWOT analysis, “Outcomes Evaluation” and “Cost – Benefit analysis” are some of the
tools we could combine, in order to bring to the surface “underground”, sociologically important, qualitative
elements (see also, DFID, 2005, United Way of America, 2000 & 2005, UNDP, Winer & Ray, 1994).
A tailor made questionnaire should provide sufficient data about: the profile of the
initiative and the debater, collaboration and communication, participation, social capital, needs and problems
related issues.
Weaver’s Triangle depicts
· The general oblectives of the organization
· The specific objectives of its programme and its members
· The field of interest
It creates an environment in which it is possible to check
· The internal cohesion in the words of the debater
· The debaters relationship with the vision of the structure which he / she belongs
to
A Contributions Assesement (and also Letters of Commitment) could depict
· grassroots contributions dynamics
· members’ capacity to contribute on their own
· a differentiation of member positions inside the organization
· the level of trust and cohesion
Channels of Participation show the different aspects and qualities of participation, how we
participate and in what context.
SWOT analysis refers to Strong Points, Weaknesses, Opportunities and Threats.
Outcomes Evaluation and Cost - Benefit analysis are much more common in evaluation and
management literature , supplementing the qualitative research with more tangible, of logistic nature, data, as far
as organizational effectiveness, performance, resource mobilization and capacities are concerned.
Conclusions
Social Economy territory is a multilaterally created field of voluntary action towards
community service providing, without the limitations exercised by market and the state.
A valid recognition approach of Social Economy institutions presupposes a degree of
conscience on their distinct nature.
As far as evaluation methods and tools are concerned, no one-sided or partial approach is proven
to be able to deliver scientifically valid results. Combinations between qualitative and quantitative methods,
combined use of different tools and interdisciplinary approaches will help researchers and Social Economy
organizations depict crucial aspects of economic and civic, voluntary activities.
Bibliography
Εθνικό Ινστιτούτο Εργασίας. (2002). Προοπτικές απασχόλησης στον τομέα της κοινωνικής οικονομίας.
Σάκκουλας.
Salamon M. Lester & Helmut K. Anheier. (1994). The emerging sector. An overview. The Johns
Hopkins Comparative Nonprofit Sector Project Studies. Baltimore.
EMES European Network. (1999). The emergence of social enterprises in Europe - A short
overview.
OECD. (2001). The Wellbeing of Nations. The role of human and social capital.
John Field. (2003). Social capital. Routledge.
LEED. East and West Cluster Conference. (2002). Panel III: Social capital and clusters.
Paper.
Woolcock M. The Place of Social Capital in Understanding Social and Economic Outcomes.
World Bank.
Woolcock M.(1999). Managing Risk, and Opportunity in Developing Economies : the Role of
Social Capital. World Bank Development Research Group.
La Ville Jean Louis & Nussens Marthe. The social enterprise: towards a theoretical socio
economic approach.
The National Economic and Social Forum. (2003). The Policy Implications of Social Capital.
Forum Report No. 28.
Barros A. (2001). Challenges of economic development. UNRIDS.
European Commission. Promoting the role of Voluntary Organisations and Foundations in
Europe. COM 1997: 241 FINAL.
OECD. (2002). Dynamising National Innovation Systems.
OECD. (2000). A new economy? The changing role of innovation and information technology in
growth.
OECD. (2001). Local partnerships for better governance.
OECD. (2001). Innovative clusters. Drivers of National Innovation Systems.
Επιτροπή των Περιφερειών. (14-3-2002). Γνωμοδότηση για τη σύμπραξη μεταξύ τοπικών και
περιφερειακών αρχών και οργανισμών κοινωνικής οικονομίας : συμβολή στην απασχόληση , την τοπική ανάπτυξη και την
κοινωνική συνοχή.
European Forum on Local Development and Employment. Rhodes 16 – 17 May 2003. Τοπική Ανάπτυξη και
Απασχόληση στην Ευρωπαϊκή Ένωση. Κοινή δράση σε τοπικό επίπεδο : περισσότερες και καλύτερες θέσεις εργασίας ,
καλύτερη διακυβέρνηση. Ευρωπαϊκό Συνέδριο – Ελληνική Προεδρία.
European Commission. Final Report of the expert group on enterprise clusters and networks.
Enterprise Directorate – General.
Anders Joest Hingel. (1993). Note on A New Model of European Development. Innovation,
Technological Development and Network – led Integration. FOP 361 – EN. Commission of the European Communities.
Science Research and Development. FAST.
Carayannis Elias , Von Zedtwitzb Maximilian. (2005). Architecting gloCal (global–local),
real-virtual incubator networks (G-RVINs) as catalysts and accelerators of entrepreneurship in transitioning and
developing economies: lessons learned and best practices from current development and business incubation
practices. Technovation – 25.
ReinickeWolfgang & Deng Francis. (2003). Critical
Choises. The United Nations, Networks and the Future of Global Governance. IDRC.
Rosenfeld Stuart.(2002). Just Clusters. RTS.
ICASO. (2002). HIV/AIDS Networking Guide.
Adevi Olusoji et al. (2000). Putting Knowledge to Work: Technical Resource Networks for
Effective Responses to HIV / AIDS. UNAIDS.
UN HIV & Development Program & UNAIDS.(2000). “Networks for Development: Lessons Learned
from Supporting National and Regional Networks on Legal, Ethical and Human Rights Dimensions of HIV/AIDS”. (Paper
retrieved from the internet).
Τσομπάνογλου Ο. Γεώργιος. Νέες Μέθοδοι και Πρακτικές Κοινωνικής Ένταξης – Πρόσφατες
Κοινωνικές Αλλαγές κατά του Κοινωνικού Αποκλεισμού και υπέρ της Τοπικής Ανάπτυξης. Οι Κοινωνικοί Συνεταιρισμοί στις
χώρες της Ευρωπαϊκής Ένωσης. Εισήγηση στο : 2ο Διεθνές Συνέδριο Κοινωνιολογίας , Θεσσαλονίκη.
OECD. (1999). Decentralizing employment policy. New trends and challenges. The Venice
Conference.
OECD. (2003). Enterpeneurship and Local Economic Development. Programme and policy
recommendations.
OECD. (2001). Cities and Regions in the New Learnig Economy.
Winer Μ. & Ray K. (1994). Collaboration Handbook: Creating, Sustaining and Enjoying the
Journey. Amherst H.Wilder Foundation.
Church Madelline at all. (2002). Participation, Relationships and Dynamic Change : New
Thinking on Evaluating the Work of International Networks. Working Paper No. 121.
Sewell M. The Use of Qualitative Interviews in Evaluation. (Article retrieved from the
internet).
InnoNet. (2000). Learning Circles Project. 15 –month report. Innonet
Organization.
InnoNet. Evaluation Workbook. Logic Model and Evaluation Training Materials. Innonet
Organization.
InnoNet. (1999). The Learning Circles Project. Nonprofit Organizational Effectiveness. A
Literature Review. Innonet Organization.
InnoNet. Program Evaluation: Igniting the Untapped Power. Innonet Organization.
Περιοδικό «The Cronicle of Philanthtropy». (2003). How Charities Learn from Evaluating
Themselves, and Tips for Measuring Results.
The Environmental Support Center and Innovation Network, Inc. Echoes from the field.
Proven Capacity Building Principles for Non Profits. Summary Report.
W.K. Kellogg Foundation. (1998). Evaluation Handbook.
Mc Namara C. (1999). Basic Guide to Programm Evaluation. MAP for Non Profits.
Sewell M. The Use of Qualitative Interviews in Evaluation. (Article retrieved from the
internet).
Connolly P. & Clein L. (1999). Getting Back in Shape: Guidelines for improving the
fitness of Nonprofits. The Conservation Company.
United Way of America. (2003). Outcome Measurement in National Health and Human Service
and Accrediting Organizations.
United Way of America. (2000). Agency Experiences With Outcome Measurement. Survey
Findings.
United Way of America. (2005). Connecting Programme Outcome Measurement to Community
Impact.
United Way of America. (2005). Outcome Measurement: Showing Results in the Nonprofit
Sector.
UNDP. (2001). Managing for Results: Monitoring and Evaluation in UNDP. A results oriented
framework. Evaluation Office.
UNDP. (2003). Evaluation of the Second Global Cooperation Framework of UNDP. Evaluation
Office.
DFID. (2005). Guidance on Evaluation and Reviw for DFID stuff. Evaluation
Department.
|